URSS.ru Online Bookstore. Editorial URSS Publishers. Moscow
Cover Korotayev A., Malkov A., Khaltourina D. Introduction to Social Macrodynamics: Compact Macromodels of the World System Growth Cover Korotayev A., Malkov A., Khaltourina D. Introduction to Social Macrodynamics: Compact Macromodels of the World System Growth
Id: 34250
14.9 EUR

Introduction to Social Macrodynamics:
Compact Macromodels of the World System Growth

URSS. 128 pp. (English). ISBN 5-484-00414-4.
White offset paper
  • Paperback

Summary

Human society is a complex nonequilibrium system that changes and develops constantly. Complexity, multivariability, and contradictoriness of social evolution lead researchers to a logical conclusion that any simplification, reduction, or neglect of the multiplicity of factors leads inevitably to the multiplication of error and to significant misunderstanding of the processes under study. The view that any simple general laws are not observed at all ...(More)with respect to social evolution has become totally predominant within the academic community, especially among those who specialize in the Humanities and who confront directly in their research all the manifold unpredictability of social processes. A way to approach human society as an extremely complex system is to recognize differences of abstraction and time scale between different levels. If the main task of scientific analysis is to detect the main forces acting on systems so as to discover fundamental laws at a sufficiently coarse scale, then abstracting from details and deviations from general rules may help to identify measurable deviations from these laws in finer detail and shorter time scales. Modern achievements in the field of mathematical modeling suggest that social evolution can be described with rigorous and sufficiently simple macrolaws.

This book discusses general regularities of the World System growth. It is shown that they can be described mathematically in a rather accurate way with rather simple models.

We draw your attention that the books marked as "Advance order is required" are not available for direct purchase. If some of such books are contained among the books you wish to buy, their price will not be immediately displayed and included in the total sum of your order. Within one day you will be informed by email about availability of such books and the final price for your order.

Contents
top
Acknowledgements
Introduction
 Chapter 1.Macrotrends of World Population Growth
 Chapter 2.A Compact Macromodel of World Population Growth
 Chapter 3.A Compact Macromodel of World Economic and Demographic Growth
 Chapter 4.A General Extended Macromodel of World Economic, Cultural, and Demographic Growth
 Chapter 5.A Special Extended Macromodel of World Economic, Cultural, and Demographic Growth
 Chapter 6.Reconsidering Weber: Literacy and "the Spirit of Capitalism"
 Chapter 7.Extended Macromodels and Demographic Transition Mechanisms
Conclusion
Appendices
 Appendix 1.World Population Growth Forecast (2005-2050)
 Appendix 2.World Population Growth Rates and Female Literacy in the 1990s: Some Observations
 Appendix 3.Hyperbolic Growth of the World Population and Kapitza's Model
Bibliography

Acknowledgements
top

First and foremost, our thanks go to the Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton. Without the first author's one-year membership in this Institute this book could hardly have been written. We are also grateful to the Russian Foundation for Basic Research for financial support of this work (projects # 04–06–8022 and # 02-06-80260).

We would like to express our special gratitude to Gregory Malinetsky, Sergey Podlazov (Institute for Applied Mathematics, Russian Academy of Sciences), Robert Graber (Truman State University), Victor de Munck (State University of New York), Duran Bell and Douglas R.White (University of California, Irvine) for their invaluable help and advice.

We would also like to thank our colleagues who offered us useful comments and insights on the subject of this book: Leonid Alaev (Oriental Institute, Russian Academy of Sciences), Herbert Barry III (University of Pittsburgh), Yuri Berzkin (Kunstkammer, St.Petersburg), Svetlana Borinskaya (Institute of General Genetics, Russian Academy of Sciences), Dmitri Bondarenko (Institute for African Studies, Russian Academy of Sciences), Michael L.Burton (University of California, Irvine), Robert L.Carneiro (American Museum of Natural History, New York), Henry J.M.Claessen (Leiden University), Marina Butovskaya (Institute of Ethnology and Anthroplogy, Russian Academy of Sciences), Dmitrij Chernavskij (Institute of Physics, Russian Academy of Sciences), Marat Cheshkov (Institute of International Economics, Russian Academy of Sciences), Loren Demerath (Centenary College), Georgi and Lubov Derlouguian (Northwestern University, Evanston), William T. Divale (City University of New York), Timothy K.Earle (Northwestern University), Leonid Grinin (Center for Social and Historical Research, Volgograd), Eric C. Jones (University of North Carolina), Natalia Komarova (University of California, Irvine), Sergey Nefedov (Russian Academy of Sciences, Ural Branch, Ekaterinburg), Nikolay Kradin (Russian Academy of Sciences, Far East Branch, Vladivostok), Vitalij Meliantsev (Institute of Asia and Africa, Moscow State University), Akop Nazaretyan (Oriental Institute, Russian Academy of Sciences), Nikolay Rozov (Novosibirsk State University), Igor Sledzevski (Institute for African Studies, Moscow), David Small (Lehigh University), Peter Turchin (University of Connecticut, Storrs), and Paul Wason (Templeton Foundation).

Needless to say, faults, mistakes, infelicities, etc., are our own responsibility.


Introduction
top

Human society is a complex nonequilibrium system that changes and develops constantly. Complexity, multivariability, and contradictoriness of social evolution lead researchers to a logical conclusion that any simplification, reduction, or neglect of the multiplicity of factors leads inevitably to the multiplication of error and to significant misunderstanding of the processes under study. The view that any simple general laws are not observed at all with respect to social evolution has become totally predominant within the academic community, especially among those who specialize in the Humanities and who confront directly in their research all the manifold unpredictability of social processes.

A way to approach human society as an extremely complex system is to recognize differences of abstraction and time scale between different levels. If the main task of scientific analysis is to detect the main forces acting on systems so as to discover fundamental laws at a sufficiently coarse scale, then abstracting from details and deviations from general rules may help to identify measurable deviations from these laws in finer detail and shorter time scales. Modern achievements in the field of mathematical modeling suggest that social evolution can be described with rigorous and sufficiently simple macrolaws. Our goal, at this stage, is to discuss a family of mathematical models whose greater specification leads to measurable variables and testable relationships.

Tremendous successes and spectacular developments in physics (especially, in comparison with other sciences) were, to a considerable degree, connected with the fact that physics managed to achieve a synthesis of mathematical methods and subject knowledge. Notwithstanding the fact that already in the classical world physical theories achieved a rather high level, it was in the modern era that the introduction of mathematics made it possible to penetrate deeper into the essence of physical laws, laying the ground for the scientific-technological revolution. However, such a synthesis was not possible without one important condition. Mathematics operates with forms and numbers, and, hence, the physical world had to be translated into the language of forms and numbers. It demanded the development of effective methods for measuring physical values and the introduction of scales and measures. Starting with the simplest variables – length, mass, time – physicists learned how to measure charge, viscosity, inductance, spin and many other variables, which are necessary for the development of the physical theory of value.

In an analogous way, a constructive synthesis of the social sciences with mathematics calls for the introduction of adequate methods for the measurement of social variables. In the social sciences, as in physics, some variables can be measured relatively easily, while the measurement of some other variables needs additional research and even the development of auxiliary models.

One social variable that is relatively well accessible to direct measurement is population size. That is why it is not surprising that the field of demography attracts the special attention of social scientists, as it suggests some hope for the development of quantitatively based scientific theories. It is remarkable that the penetration of mathematical methods into biology began, to a considerable extent, with the description of population dynamics.

The basic measurability of data is quite evident here; what is more, the basic equation for the description of demographic dynamics is also rather evident, as it stems from the conservation law:

dN/dt = B – D, (0.1)

where N is the number of people, B is the number of births, and D is the number of deaths in the unit of time. However, at the microlevel it turns out that both the number of deaths and number of births depend heavily on a huge number of social parameters, including the "human factor" – decisions made by individual people that are very difficult to formalize.

In addition to this, equation (0.1) does not take into account the spatial movement of people; hence, it should be extended:

dN/dt = B – Ddiv J, (0.1')

where vector J corresponds to the migration current. In this case the problem becomes even more complicated, as migration processes are even more likely to be influenced by external factors.

That is why any formal description of demographic processes at the microlevel confronts serious problems associated first of all with the lack of sufficient research on formal social laws connecting economic, political, ethical and other factors that affect individual and small group (e.g., household or nuclear family) behavior. Thus, at the moment the only available approach is macrolevel description that does not go into the fine details of demographic processes and describes dynamics of very large human populations, which is influenced by the human factor at a significantly coarser level of abstraction and on a longer time-scale.

Biological processes of birth and death are characteristic not only of people, but also of any animals. That is why a rather natural step is to try to describe demographic models using population models developed within biology (see, e.g., Riznichenko 2002).

The basic model describing animal population dynamics is the logistic model, suggested by Verhulst (1838):

dN/dt = rN(1 – N/K), (0.2)

which can be also presented in the following way:

dN/dt = (a1N) – (a2N + bN2), (0.3)

where a1N corresponds to the number of births B, and a2N + bN2 corresponds to the number of deaths in equation (0.1); r, K, a1, a2, b are positive coefficients connected between themselves by the following relationships:

r = a1 – a2 and b = r/K, (0.4)

The logic of equation (0.3) is as follows: fertility a_1 is a constant; thus, the number of births B = a1N is proportional to the population size, natural death rate a2 is also considered to be constant, whereas quadratic addition bN2 in expression for full number of deaths D = a1N+bN2 appears due to the resource limitation, which does not let population grow infinitely. Coefficient b is called the coefficient of interspecies competition.

As a result, the population dynamics described by the logistic equation has the following characteristics. At the beginning, when the size of the animal population size is low, we observe an exponential growth with exponent r = a1a2. Then, as the ecological niche is being filled, the population growth slows down, and finally the population comes to the constant level K.

The value of parameter K, called the carrying capacity of an ecological niche for the given population, is of principal importance. This value determines the equilibrium state in population dynamics for the given resource limitations and controls the limits of its growth.

Another well known population dynamics model is Lotka – Volterra one (Lotka 1925; Volterra 1926), denoted also as the "prey – predator" model. It describes dynamics of populations of two interacting species, one of which constitutes the main food resource for the other, and consists of two equations of type (0.1):

dx/dt = Ax – Bxy, dy/dt = Cx – Dxy, (0.5)

where x is the size of the prey population, y is the size of the predator population; A, B, C, D are coefficients.

This model, like (0.2), assumes that the number of prey births is proportional to their population size. The number of predator deaths is also proportional to their population size. As regards prey death rates and predator fertility rates, we are dealing here with a system effect. Prey animals are assumed to die mainly because of contacts with predators, whereas the predator fertility rates depend on the availability of food – prey animals. The model assumes that the average number of contacts between prey animals and predators depends mainly on the size of both populations and suggests expression Bxy for the number of prey deaths and Cxy for the number of predator births.

This model generates a cyclical dynamics. The growth of the prey population leads to the growth of the predator population; the growth of predator population leads to the decrease of the prey animal number; decrease of the prey population leads to the decrease of the predators' number; and when the number of predators is very small, the prey population can grow very rapidly.

The population models described above are used very widely in biological research. It seems reasonable to suppose that, as humans have a biological nature, some relations similar to the ones described above, or their analogues could be valid for humans too.

In deep prehistory, when human ancestors did not differ much from animals, models (0.2) – (0.4) may have been applied to them without any significant reservations. However, with the appearance of a new human environment, the sociotechnological one, the direct application of those models does not appear to be entirely adequate. In particular, model (0.2) assumes carrying capacity to be determined by exogenous factors; however, human history shows that over the course of time the carrying capacity of land has tended to increase in a rather significant way. Hence, in long-range perspective carrying capacity cannot be assumed to be constant and determined entirely by exogenous conditions. Humans are capable of transforming those conditions affecting carrying capacity.

As regards model (0.4), it has an extremely limited applicability to humans in its direct form, as humans learned how to defend themselves effectively from predators at very early stages of their evolution; hence, humans cannot function as "prey" in this model. On the other hand, humans learned how not to depend on the fluctuations of prey animals populations, hence, they cannot function as predators because in model (0.4) predators are very sensitive to the variations of prey animal numbers (This model could still have some limited direct applicability to a very few cases of highly specialized hunters).

However, model (0.4) may find a new non-traditional application in demographic models. In particular it may be applied to the description of demographic cycles that have been found in historical dynamics of almost all the agrarian societies, for which relevant data are available. The population plays here the role of "prey", whereas the role of "predator" belongs to sociopolitical instability, internal warfare, famines and epidemics whose probability increases when an increasing population approaches the carrying capacity ceiling (for detail see, e.g., Korotayev, Malkov and Khaltourina 2005: 211–54). Demographic cycles are by themselves a very interesting subject for mathematical research, and they have been studied rather actively in recent years (Usher 1989; Chu and Lee 1994; Malkov and Sergeev 2002, 2004; Malkov et al. 2002; Malkov 2002, 2003, 2004; Malkov, Selunskaja, and Sergeev 2005; Turchin 2003; Turchin and Korotayev 2006; Nefedov 2002a; 2004; Korotayev, Malkov and Khaltourina 2005 etc.)

As is well known in complexity studies, chaotic dynamics at the microlevel can generate a highly deterministic macrolevel behavior (e.g., Chernavskij 2004). To describe behavior of a few dozen gas molecules in a closed vessel we need very complex mathematical models; and these models would still be unable to predict long-run dynamics of such a system due to inevitable irreducible chaotic components. However, the behavior of zillions of gas molecules can be described with extremely simple sets of equations, which are capable of predicting almost perfectly the macrodynamics of all the basic parameters (just because of chaotic behavior at microlevel). Of course, one cannot fail to wonder whether a similar set of regularities would not also be observed in the human world too. That is, cannot a few very simple equations account for an extremely high proportion of all the macrovariation with respect to the largest possible social system – the World System?


About the authors
top

Andrey Korotayev is Acting Director and Professor of the "Anthropology of the East" Center, Russian State University for the Humanities, Moscow. He also chairs the Advisory Committee in Cross-Cultural Research for "Social Dynamics and Evolution" Program at the University of California, Irvine. He received his PhD from Manchester University, and Doctor of Sciences degree from the Russian Academy of Sciences. He is author of over 200 scholarly publications, including Ancient Yemen (Oxford University Press, 1995), Pre-Islamic Yemen (Harrassowitz Verlag, 1996), Social Evolution (Nauka, 2003), World Religions and Social Evolution of the Old World Oikumene Civilizations: a Cross-Cultural Perspective (Mellen, 2004), Origins of Islam (OGI, 2005), Long-Term Political-Demographic Dynamics of Egypt: Trends and Cycles (Nauka, 2006).

Artemy Malkov is Research Fellow of the Keldysh Institute for Applied Mathematics, Russian Academy of Sciences from where he received his PhD. His research concentrates on the modeling of social and historical processes, spatial historical dynamics, genetic algorithms, cellular automata. He has authored over 35 scholarly publications, including such articles as "History and Mathematical Modeling" (2000), "Mathematical Modeling of Geopolitical Processes" (2002), "Mathematical Analysis of Social Structure Stability" (2004) that have been published in the leading Russian academic journals.

Daria Khaltourina is Research Fellow of the Center for Regional Studies, Russian Academy of Sciences (from where she received her PhD) and Associate Professor at the Russian Academy for Civil Service. Her research concentrates on complex social systems, countercrisis management, cross-cultural and cross-national research, demography, sociocultural anthropology, and mathematical modeling of social processes. She has authored over 40 scholarly publications, including such articles as "Concepts of Culture in Cross-National and Cross-Cultural Perspectives" (World Cultures 12, 2001), "Methods of Cross-Cultural Research and Modern Anthropology" (Etnograficheskoe obozrenie 5, 2002), "Russian Demographic Crisis in Cross-National Perspective" (in Russia and the World. Washington, DC: Kennan Institute, forthcoming).


Review
top

Review of Andrey Korotayev, Artemy Malkov, and Daria Khaltourina, Introduction to Social Macrodynamics (Three Volumes). Moscow: URSS, 2006.

Robert Bates Graber
Professor Emeritus of Anthropology Division of Social Science Truman State University

(published in Social Evolution & History. Vol. 7 (2008). Issue 2. Forthcoming)

This interesting work is an English translation, by the authors and in three brief volumes, of an amended and expanded version of their Russian work published in 2005. Andrey Korotayev is Director of the "Anthropology of the East" Center at the Russian State University for the Humanities; Artemy Malkov is Research Fellow of the Keldysh Institute for Applied Mathematics; and Daria Khaltourina is Research Fellow of the Center for Regional Studies. By way of full disclosure, I should state that I have enjoyed not only making the acquaintance of the first and third authors at professional meetings, but also the opportunity to offer comments on earlier versions of some parts of this English translation. In terms coined recently by Peter Turchin, the first volume focuses on "millennial trends," the latter two on "secular cycles" a century or two in duration.

The first volume's subtitle is Compact Models of the World System Growth (CMWSG hereafter). Its mathematical basis is the standard hyperbolic growth model, in which a quantity's proportional (or percentage) growth is not constant, as in exponential growth, but is proportional to the quantity itself. For example, if a quantity growing initially at 1 percent per unit time triples, it will by then be growing at 3 percent per unit time. The remarkable claim that human population has grown, over the long term, according to this model was first advanced in a semi-serious paper of 1960 memorably entitled "Doomsday: Friday, 13 November, A.D. 2026" (von Foerster, Mora, and Amiot, 1960). Admitting that this curve notably fails to fit world population since 1962, chapter 1 of CMWSG attempts to salvage the situation by showing that the striking linearity of the declining rates since that time, considered with respect to population, can be identified as still hyperbolic, but in inverse form. Chapter 2 finds that the hyperbolic curve provides a very good fit to world population since 500 BCE. The authors believe this reflects the existence, from that time on, of a single, somewhat integrated World System; and they find they can closely simulate the pattern of actual population growth by assuming that although population is limited by technology (Malthus), technology grows in proportion to population (Kuznets and Kremer). Chapter 3 argues that world GDP has grown not hyperbolically but quadratically, and that this is because its most dynamic component contains two factors, population and per-capita surplus, each of which has grown hyperbolically. To this demographic and economic picture chapter 4 adds a "cultural" dimension by ingeniously incorporating a literacy multiplier into the differential equation for absolute population growth (with respect to time) such that the degree to which economic surplus expresses itself as population growth depends on the proportion of the population that is literate: when almost nobody is literate, economic surplus generates population growth; when almost everybody is literate, it does not. This allows the authors' model to account nicely for the dramatic post-1962 deviation from the "doomsday" (hyperbolic) trajectory. It also paves the way for a more specialized model stressing the importance, in the modern world, of human-capital development (chapter 5). Literacy's contribution to economic development is neatly and convincingly linked, in chapter 6, to Weber's famous thesis about Protestantism's contribution to the rise of modern capitalism. Chapter 7 cogently unravels and elucidates the complex role of literacy male, female, and overall in the demographic transition. In effect, the "doomsday" population trajectory carried the seeds of its own aborting:

the maximum values of population growth rates cannot be reached without a certain level of economic development, which cannot be achieved without literacy rates reaching substantial levels. Hence, again almost by definition the fact that the [world] system reached the maximum level of population growth rates implies that . . . literacy [had] attained such a level that the negative impact of female literacy on fertility rates would increase to such an extent that the population growth rates would start to decline (CMWSG: 104).

The second volume is subtitled Secular Cycles and Millennial Trends (SCMT hereafter). Chapter 1 stresses that demographic cycles are not, as often has been thought, unique to China and Europe, but are associated with complex agrarian systems in general; and it reviews previous approaches to modeling such cycles. Due to data considerations, the lengthy chapter 2 focuses on China. In the course of assessing previous work, the authors, though writing of agrarian societies in particular, characterize nicely what is, in larger view, the essential dilemma reached by every growing human population:

In agrarian society within fifty years such population growth [0.6 percent per year] leads to diminishing of per capita resources, after which population growth slows down; then either solutions to resource problems (through some innovations) are found and population growth rate increases, or (more frequently) such solutions are not found (or are not adequate), and population growth further declines (sometimes below zero) (SCMT: 61-62).

(Indeed, for humans, technological solutions that raise carrying capacity are always a presumptive alternative to demographic collapse; therefore, asserting or even proving that a particular population "exceeded its carrying capacity" is not sufficient to account logically for the collapse of either a political system or an entire civilizations.) Interestingly, the authors find evidence that China's demographic cycles, instead of simply repeating themselves, tended to increase both in duration and in maximum pre-collapse population. In a brief chapter 3 the authors present a detailed mathematical model which, while not simulating these trends, does simulate (1) the S-shaped logistic growth of population (with the effects of fluctuating annual harvests smoothed by the state's functioning as a tax collector and famine-relief agency); (2) demographic collapse due to increase in banditry and internal warfare; and (3) an "intercycle" due to lingering effects of internal warfare. Chapter 4 offers a most creative rebuttal of recent arguments against population pressure's role in generating pre-industrial warfare, arguing that a slight negative correlation, in synchronic cross-cultural data, is precisely what such a causal role would be expected to produce (due to time lags) when warfare frequency and population density are modeled as predator and prey, respectively, using the classic Lotka-Volterra equations. Chapter 4 also offers the authors' ambitious attempt to directly articulate secular cycles and millennial trends. Ultimately they produce a model that, unlike the basic one in chapter 3, simulates key trends observed in the Chinese data in chapter 2:

the later cycles are characterized by a higher technology, and, thus, higher carrying capacity and population, which, according to Kremer's technological development equation embedded into our model, produces higher rates of technological (and, thus, carrying capacity) growth. Thus, with every new cycle it takes the population more and more time to approach the carrying capacity ceiling to a critical extent; finally it "fails" to do so, the technological growth rates begin to exceed systematically the population growth rates, and population escapes from the "Malthusian trap" (SCMT: 130).

The third volume is subtitled Secular Cycles and Millennial Trends in Africa (SCMTA hereafter).It is divided into two parts, the first of which is devoted to Egypt in the 1st through 18th centuries CE (chapters 1-6); the second, to postcolonial tropical Africa (chapters 7-8). The first part argues that while Egypt's population probably increased over the period in question, the increase was modest compared to that of other agrarian societies. This modesty the authors ascribe to the remarkable brevity of Egypt's political-demographic cycles, which they estimate at averaging around ninety years little more than half as long as China's. With such brief cycles, collapse repeatedly occurred long before carrying capacities were approached. Strongly inspired by Peter Turchin's work but hewing more closely to insights of the anachronistic 14th-century cultural evolutionist Ibn Khaldun, the authors find that these brief cycles can be modeled by including climatic fluctuation and, especially, the rapid reproduction of high-consumption elites due to polygyny. They estimate the annual growth rate for Egyptian elites at 4 percent per year, the rate for commoners (monogamous) at only 1 percent per year a recipe for rapid political-demographic crisis and collapse, since elites of course depend on the taxation of commoners!

The second part of SCMTA describes the impact of modernization on political-demographic cycles. The authors find that low nutrition predicts political instability and civil war in African nations; for prevention, they recommend especially the diversification of national economies, and the fostering of education to promote economic development. Concerning the underlying causes of historical events, they quote John Maynard Keynes writing in 1920:

The great events of history are often due to secular changes in the growth of population and other fundamental economic causes, which, escaping by their gradual character the notice of contemporary observers, are attributed to the follies of statesmen or the fanaticism of atheists (quoted in SCMTA: 113). Some aspects of this work are easy to criticize. The reporting of probabilities with sixteen zeros to the right of the decimal point will strike as gratuitous those readers who consider .001, .01, or even .05 sufficient to render randomness an implausible explanation for a result, especially when, as here, the danger of erroneously rejecting the null hypothesis (alpha or Type I error) is clearly preferable to the premature truncation of inquiry that could result from erroneous failure to reject the null (beta or Type II error). More importantly, one would like to have seen more attention given to the problems that attend using regression with time-series data. Values in a variable's time series tend to be affected by adjacent values ("autocorrelation"), a condition that violates one of the assumptions underlying the ordinary-least-squares model and that regularly results, for regressions on time itself (e.g., population plotted against time), in exaggerated R-squared magnitudes and significance levels; similar exaggeration results for regressions of a time-trending variable on one or more other time-trending variables (e.g., population growth rate plotted against population). The frequent appearance, in the book's graphs, of long runs of data points on the same side of a theoretical line or curve is a symptom of autocorrelation; and the book's regressions of trending variables on other trending variables do not appear to have been protected from this source of spuriousness by inclusion of time itself as an independent variable in the regression equations. The hyperbolic curve, moreover, is not systematically compared here with serious competitors. For these reasons the hyperbolic curve's superiority, as a description of human population history, remains by no means beyond question (cf. Cohen 1995: chapter 5 and appendix 6).

Important questions remain, too, about the tenability of the Kuznets-Kremer assumptions appealing as they are to some of us offered to theoretically account for the hyperbolic model's applicability to human population history. For example, the key assumption that technological growth tends to keep pace with population growth appears problematic enough to warrant perhaps greater caution than the authors express. Also, one would like to see a better fit between the abstract global model on one hand, and what we know about the growth rates for particular populations on the other. Since particular populations seldom sustain even exponential growth for very long, explaining sustained hyperbolic growth globally apparently requires invoking the spread, from population to population, of the demographic transition's first phase (cf. CMWSG: 92-93; SCMTA: 116-117). This is for recent centuries only; to cover the pre-industrial period, the authors posit five somewhat intricate and interrelated mechanisms, one of which again relies on diffusion (the "innovation diffusion" mechanism) (SCMTA: 140-141). It seems somewhat awkward, however, to rely so much on diffusion from donor to recipient regional populations, sometimes over considerable time periods, given that the Kuznets-Kremer assumptions appear to ascribe the (apparently) hyperbolic shape of long-term global population growth to direct and continuous interaction, within a single world-system population, between a single technological base and a single inventive potential (both seen as proportional, quantitatively, to population itself).

While the translation's English is often less than felicitous, it is quite clear; the few typographical errors I noted were not of a kind to create misunderstanding. The authors are to be commended, I think, for putting most of the mathematics "up front" rather than tucked away in appendices, as publishers are wont to urge. (There are technical appendices three in CMWSG, two in SCMT, and one in SCMTA; but their function is by no means to keep the text itself free of math.) Cultural evolutionism is still near the beginning of the long process of becoming a mathematical science; to that extent, the medium of this book is, if perhaps not the message, certainly a message (Carneiro 2003: 285-286)!

Even more generally, this work vigorously asserts the value of studying social and cultural evolution as such. Noting the "almost total disenchantment with the evolutionary approach in the social sciences as a whole" (SCMT: 140), the authors perspicuously compare the resulting stultification to the fate that "would have stricken physicists if a few centuries ago they had decided that there is no real thing such as gas, that gas is a mental construction, and that one should start with such a simple' thing as a mathematical model of a few free-floating molecules in a closed vessel" (SCMT: 140, note 6).

Thirty years ago, Mark Nathan Cohen wrote, "It has been my observation that simple hypotheses boldly defended are often the best teaching tools and the best spurs to research" (Cohen 1977: ix) Aside from the difficulties we all encounter, sooner or later, comprehending mathematics (we differ only in when, not in whether, the difficulties begin), this book's theses are simple; and they are nothing if not "boldly defended"! In sum, this work deserves attention from anyone interested in cultural evolutionism's scientific prospects, and close study indeed by anyone hoping to contribute to this field's development from a mathematical point of view.

REFERENCES

Carneiro, R. L. 2003. Evolutionism in Cultural Anthropology: A Critical History. Boulder, CO: Westview.

Cohen, J. E. 1995. How Many People Can the Earth Support? New York: W. W. Norton.

Cohen, M. N. 1977. The Food Crisis in Prehistory: Overpopulation and the Origins of Agriculture. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

Foerster, H. von, P. Mora, and L. Amiot 1960. Doomsday: Friday, 13 November, A.D. 2026. Science 132: 1291-1295.

Information / Order
136 pp. (English). Paperback. 12.9 EUR

The Moscow Mathematical Journal (MMJ) is an international quarterly published (paper and electronic) by the Independent University of Moscow, together with the Mathematical Department of the Higher School of Econonics and Moscow Center for Continuous Mathematical Education, and distributed worldwide... (More)


Information / Order
264 pp. (English). Hardcover. 49.9 EUR

Information / Order
376 pp. (English). Hardcover. 110.9 EUR

The present book includes the first full catalogue of Russian porcelain of the 18th and 19th centuries from the Vladimir Tsarenkov Collection. The collection has over 250 outstanding works by leading Russian manufactories — the Imperial Porcelain Factory in Saint Petersburg and the Gardner Porcelain... (More)


Information / Order
Razmakhnin M. Radar made easy.
270 pp. (English). Hardcover. Advance order is required  29.9 EUR

Information / Order
176 pp. (English). Paperback. 12.9 EUR

New textbooks must be based on a new principle: there is as much science in natural science as there is science actually in it, in chemistry — chemistry, in physics — physics. There are many roads in science. In order to compare different approaches to the study of physics, we will use the popular Russian... (More)


Information / Order
130 pp. (English). Paperback. 32.9 EUR

Written by the science supervisor of the Institute of High Pressure Physics of Russian Academy of Sciences, the ABCs of High Pressure Science contains brief information explaining the terms and concepts adopted by professionals involved in research in the field of high pressure, be it physics, geology,... (More)


Information / Order
288 pp. (English). Paperback. 25.9 EUR

Information / Order
232 pp. (English). Paperback. 29.9 EUR

Corr. USSR Academy of Sciences KI Shchelkine in the popular series of essays is about the structure of atoms and atomic nuclei of matter and antimatter, on nuclear forces, the structure of nucleons. The book gives an idea of ​​the strong, electromagnetic and weak interactions, parity, its non-conservation... (More)


Information / Order
352 pp. (English). Hardcover. 13.9 EUR

Information / Order
200 pp. (English). Paperback. 13.9 EUR

The Moscow Mathematical Journal (MMJ) is an international quarterly published (paper and electronic) by the Independent University of Moscow, together with the Mathematical Department of the Higher School of Econonics and Moscow Center for Continuous Mathematical Education, and distributed worldwide... (More)